You are here:
AustLII >>
Databases >>
Federal Judicial Scholarship >>
2006 >>
[2006] FedJSchol 24
[Database Search]
[Name Search]
[Recent Articles]
[Noteup]
[Download]
[Help]
French, Justice Robert --- "Authorisation and public benefit - playing with categories of meaningless reference?" (FCA) [2006] FedJSchol 24
4TH
ANNUAL UNIVERSITY OF SOUTH AUSTRALIA
TRADE PRACTICES WORKSHOP
20-21 October 2006
Barossa Valley Resort
AUTHORISATION AND PUBLIC BENEFIT – PLAYING WITH
CATEGORIES OF MEANINGLESS REFERENCE?
Justice R S French
Federal Court of
Australia
Introduction
- Pogo
Possum, a cartoon character of the 1940’s, created by American cartoonist,
Walt Kelly, is credited with the well known
words:
‘We have met the enemy and he is us.’
[1]
The saying can be reframed to apply to very broad legal standards whose scope
and content are left to the discretion and perhaps imagination
of
decision-makers. Of them we can say:
‘We have met the standard and it is
us.’
- ‘Public
benefit’, as a statutory standard, seems to fit that description. It
opens the door to a multi-dimensional universe
of discourse. Taken in isolation
it is capable of meaning anything, and of attracting any criteria of evaluation
that the person
invoking it thinks are good. Under the Trade Practices Act
1974 (Cth) it informs the exercise of the power of the Australian
Competition and Consumer Commission (the Commission) to authorise conduct
which
could otherwise contravene competition law. It may be ‘weighed’
against incommensurable detriments. This paper
considers the nature of the
decision-making process involved in applying the public benefit test and in a
general way the limits
applicable to it. It is helpful to begin with a brief
reference to some historical analogues and antecedents.
Public
benefit, public interest and other like terms
- There
is nothing new under the sun. It is a long and honourable tradition of the
judge-made law to develop criteria that require
policy-based approaches to the
decision of legal questions. Concepts such as ‘reasonableness’ in
the law of tort, its
now deceased companion ‘proximity’,
‘unconscionable conduct’ in equity and ‘legitimate
expectation’
in public law are all examples. Statute law has multiplied
beyond number the cases in which administrators and judges are invited
to apply
similar language. Such terms do not define legal rules. Rather they confer
power on administrators and judges to make
decisions based on criteria which
they develop for themselves within a vaguely defined normative universe of
discourse.
- Judicial
use of ‘public benefit’ and like expressions as a standard of legal
excuse or justification has a history. In
19th century
England, for example, it was an actionable nuisance for a riparian land owner
partly to obstruct a publicly navigable river
by erecting mooring posts or
jetties on the riverbed. The nuisance could be excused if the conduct generated
a public benefit.
There was debate about the scope of that concept. One view
was that if the construction meant goods could be brought to market in
better
condition and at smaller expense, the public would
benefit.[2] A narrower
test, which prevailed, was that the benefit must be to the same public who used
the river and must be a direct
benefit.[3] It had to
be of a similar nature to the nuisance showing that, on the balance of
convenience and inconvenience the public at that
place would not only lose
nothing but gain something by the
erection.[4]
- A
closer analogy for present purposes is found in the common law doctrine relating
to covenants in restraint of trade. All such covenants
are ‘prima facie
unenforceable at common law and are enforceable only if they are reasonable with
respect to the interests
of the parties concerned and of the
public’.[5] A
classic formulation by Lord Macnaghten was
thus:
‘It is a sufficient justification, and indeed it is the only
justification, if the restriction is reasonable – reasonable
that is, in
reference to the interests of the parties concerned and reasonable in reference
to the interests of the public, so framed
and so guarded as to afford adequate
protection to the party in whose favour it is imposed, while at the same time it
is in no way
injurious to the public.’
[6]
- A
conservative approach to public interest would assess whether a restraint is
reasonable, not by reference to potential economic
advantages and disadvantages
to the public, but by asking whether it amounts to an unreasonable limitation of
liberty to trade.[7] A
less restrictive view is that the public interest covers ‘the public
welfare’ or ‘general utility’ to
the public which as Chitty on
Contracts says is:
‘A meaning which, though compelling the court to secure a difficult
balance between this objective of public benefit and the
other one of fairness
to the individual trader, would be the modern equivalent of the
‘pernicious monopoly’ of ancient
times and would harmonise well with
modern statutory philosophy against monopolistic practices that are inconsistent
with welfare
objectives.’
[8]
- The
Monopolies and Mergers Commission in the United Kingdom set up under the
Monopolies and Restrictive Practices (Inquiry and Control) Act 1948 was
empowered to make orders in relation to ‘monopoly conditions’
operating against the public interest in connection
with the supply, processing
and export of goods. The Restrictive Trade Practices Act 1956 (UK)
authorised the Restrictive Practices Court to declare whether restrictive
agreements affecting production, supply and processing
of goods were against the
public interest and, if so, to declare the restrictive agreements void. The
system was extended to services
by the Restrictive Trade Practices Act
1976.[9] The 1976
Act required the Restrictive Practices Court to be satisfied that a restriction
was not unreasonable having regard to
the balance between circumstances of
benefit to the public and any detriment to the public resulting from, or likely
to result from,
the operation of the restriction. The Court had to consider
whether removal of the restriction would deny to the public as purchasers,
consumers and users of goods ‘specific and substantial benefits and
advantages’. In so doing it had to consider a future
with and without the
restriction. Interestingly, there was debate about whether the parties to a
restrictive agreement were part
of the public whose benefit could be
considered.[10] It
was uncontroversial that if prices were lower with the restriction than under
free competition without the restriction there
was a specific and substantial
benefit to be
lost.[11]
- A
similar balancing test was established under the Resale Prices Act 1976.
Goods might be exempted under that Act if it appeared to the Restrictive
Practices Court that the detriment to the public as consumers
or users of goods
flowing from maintenance of minimum resale prices would be outweighed by the
detriment if those prices were not
maintained.[12]
Detriments included effects on the quality and variety of goods available for
sale. Health and safety issues and services provided
with or after sales were
also specified.
- It
is likely that the functions of the former Restrictive Practices Court in
England would be viewed in Australia as administrative
rather than judicial,
more akin to those of the Australian Competition Tribunal, than those of a
Court. The concept of ‘court’
in England and of ‘judge’
seems wider than in Australia confined as it is, at the Federal level, by
constitutional concepts
of judicial power.
- In
Australia the Trade Practices Act 1965 (Cth) empowered the Trade
Practices Tribunal to prohibit anti-competitive conduct ‘against the
public interest’. This
covered matters such as the needs and interests of
consumers, employees, producers, distributors, importers, exporters, proprietors
and investors. It also covered the needs of small business, the promotion of
new enterprises and the need to achieve the full and
efficient use and
distribution of labour, capital, materials, industrial capacity, industrial
know-how and other resources. Efficient
and economical means of production,
provision, treatment and distribution of goods and services of a quality,
quantity and price
to best meet the requirements of domestic and overseas
markets was a relevant matter. So too was the ability of Australian producers
and exporters to compete in overseas
markets.[13]
- Public
interest and public benefit criteria have a long history in the law. The idea
of using them to excuse or authorise anti-competitive
conduct has been in
existence in one form or another for a long time. The interesting feature of
the public benefit criterion for
authorisation under Australia’s law
however is its width. That raises, at the outset, a rule of law question about
its limits.
It also raises the question whether authorisation is essentially
administrative in character and whether it could conceivably be
undertaken by a
Court. Before turning to those questions it is useful to give a brief overview
of the authorisation provisions.
Overview of the authorisation
provisions
- Australia’s
original competition legislation, the Australian Industries Preservation Act
1906 (Cth), was modelled on the Sherman Act 1890 (US). It did not
provide for authorisation to disapply any of its prohibitions. It included a
requirement that the Court be satisfied
that conduct be ‘to the detriment
of the public’. In the Trade Practices Act 1965 there was a
procedure established for registration and examination of anti-competitive
agreements or practices which could be prohibited
if held by the Trade Practices
Tribunal to be against the ‘public interest’.
- Under
the Trade Practices Act 1974, as originally enacted, certain conduct,
which might otherwise be prohibited under Pt IV, could be authorised if it were
likely to result in a ‘substantial’ benefit to the public which
would not ‘otherwise
be available’. When the Act was reviewed in
1976 the Swanson Committee recommended that the test be made less onerous. The
Committee said that competitive behaviour is to be valued for the benefits that
it brings to the community at large. It went on:
‘However, if in a given case it can be shown that public benefits,
ie,not merely benefits to the parties to the restrictive
conduct, are available,
and that those benefits outweigh the benefits to the public foregone by the
absence or restriction of competition,
then that conduct should be permitted to
continue. In other words, we still favour the maintenance of the primary
position that
competitive behaviour is to be preferred, but that many who engage
in restrictions of competition should be able to obtain an authorisation
if they
can show that on balance there are public benefits that outweigh the effects on
the public of the restrictions on competition.’
[14]
Following the 1977 amendments the public benefit tests under the
authorisation provisions of the Act entered what is substantially
their present
form.
- The
Trade Practices Act 1974 is made under the power conferred on the
Parliament of the Commonwealth to make orders with respect to foreign
corporations and trading
and financial corporations formed within Australia. It
also relies, in its extended operation, upon a variety of other specific
heads
of legislative power.
- The
brief long title of the Act describes it as ‘An Act relating to certain
Trade Practices’ and its stated object, inserted
in 1995, is ‘... to
enhance the welfare of Australians through the promotion of competition and fair
trading and provision
for consumer protection’. To that end, although its
core provisions predated the objects statement by 21 years of the Act’s
prior history, Part IV prohibits a range of anti-competitive conduct under the
global title ‘Restrictive Trade Practices’.
- The
classes of conduct prohibited by Part IV include:
- Contracts,
arrangements or understandings which have the purpose or have or are likely to
have the effect of substantially lessening
competition (s 45).
- Contracts,
arrangements or understandings fixing, maintaining or controlling prices (ss 45
and 45A).
- Secondary
boycotts and boycotts affecting overseas trade and commerce (ss 45D and
45DB).
- Contracts,
arrangements or understandings preventing or hindering the supply or acquisition
of goods or services (s 45E).
- Misuse
of market power (ss 46 and 46A).
- Exclusive
dealing (s 47).
- Resale
price maintenance (s 48);
- Acquisition
of shares or assets that would have the effect, or be likely to have the effect,
of substantially lessening competition
(s 50).
- Part
VII of the Act empowers the Commission to authorise conduct which might
otherwise contravene certain of the provisions of Pt
IV. When so authorised the
relevant prohibitions do not apply to that conduct. The power to authorise such
conduct is expressed
to be subject to a public benefit test, variously
formulated, which is to be assessed by the Commission. The provisions which can
be disapplied in this way are ss 45, 45A, 45D, 45DA, 45DB, 47, 48 and 50.
Misuse of market power contrary to s 46 cannot be authorised.
- The
power to authorise conduct is conferred on the Commission by s 88 of the Act.
Its effect in relation to the disapplication of
the prohibitions under Pt IV is
also set out in that section. The tests for authorisation are contained in s
90.
- The
tests for authorisation fall into three broad
categories[15] and
here the term ‘conduct’ is used as including contracts,
arrangements, understandings and covenants, as well as conduct
as defined in the
Act:
- That
the proposed conduct would result, or be likely to result, in a benefit to the
public and that benefit would outweigh the detriment
to the public constituted
by any lessening of competition that would result, or be likely to result, if
the proposed conduct were
engaged in (ss 90(6) and 90(7)). This test applies to
s 45 and related provisions importing a competition test for their
contravention.
- That
the proposed conduct will result, or be likely to result, in such a benefit to
the public that it should be allowed (s 90(8)).
This test applies to exclusive
dealing in exclusionary provisions, boycotts and resale price maintenance where
a competition test
is not applicable.
- The
third test is applicable to acquisitions covered by s 50 and requires that in
all the circumstances the proposed acquisition would
result, or be likely to
result, in such a benefit to the public that the acquisition should be allowed
to take place (s 90(90)).
- Only
in respect of the authorisation of s 50 conduct are there factors which the
Commission is expressly required to take into account
as benefits to the public.
They are:
(i) a significant increase in the real value of exports;
(ii) a significant substitution of domestic products for imported goods.
The Commission is also required to take into account all other relevant
matters that relate to the international competitiveness of
any Australian
industry. None of this exhausts the concept of public benefit for the purposes
of determining whether a proposed
merger or acquisition should be
authorised.
Public benefit and Public law
- The
width of the concept of public benefit was declared by the Trade Practices
Tribunal in
QCMA[16] in
1976 when it said:
‘... we would not wish to rule out of consideration any argument coming
within the widest possible conception of public benefit.
This we see as
anything of value to the community generally, any contribution to the aims
pursued by the society including as one
of its principal elements (in the
context of trade practices legislation) the achievement of the economic goals of
efficiency and
progress.’
[17]
The Tribunal added that the wider concept of public benefit had to be
‘severely qualified by reference to the requirements that
it be the
result, or likely result, (in that case of the acquisition), (2) that it was not
otherwise available; and (3) that it was
‘substantial’’. The
latter two requirements do not now apply. The severity of the qualification is
questionable.
- The
concept of public benefit applies, under the Trade Practices Act 1974
(Cth) (the Act), in the context of authorisation and to that extent is limited
by its procedural and subject matter setting. It
must be ‘public’,
a term which has been construed as referring to the Australian
public.[18] Beyond
that there is no express limit on its content. It has the ring of an unfettered
discretion strengthened as appears below
by the other wide ranging criteria
which the Commission is to apply.
- It
is an important principle of Australian public law deriving from concepts of the
rule of law and our constitutional framework that
there is no such thing as an
unfettered discretion. The common law principle was stated by Lord Denning MR
in 1971:
‘The discretion of a statutory body is never unfettered. It is a
discretion which is to be exercised according to law.’
[19]
Kirby J put the same proposition in its Australian context when he said:
‘No parliament of Australia could confer absolute power on
anyone.’
[20]
-
The exercise of official power in Australia is derived from statutes made under
the written constitutions of the Commonwealth and
the States and, in the cases
of executive or prerogative power, directly from those constitutions. But no
official power can exceed
the limits set by those instruments. A truly
unfettered discretion conferred by a Commonwealth law could travel beyond the
limits
of the constitutional head of power upon which the statute creating it is
based. It is a general principle of interpretation that
every statutory power
is confined by the subject matter, scope and purpose of the statute which
creates it.[21]
The internal logic of the statute requires no less.
- The
‘public benefit’ factor in s 90 is confined to by its application to
the authorisation of limited classes of conduct
and the requirement that it be
causally related to the conduct authorised. But within those constraints the
range of matters that
may be brought into account under the rubric of public
benefit is not in terms limited. Many, if not most cases will focus on
questions
of economic efficiency. But the scope and purposes of the Act and
even its stated objects do not impose any well-defined constraint
upon matters
which may be considered as benefits.
- The
word ‘benefit’ itself of course may suggest a link to some sort of
community sense of what is a good thing and what
is a bad thing. If conduct
which it is sought to authorise has benefits but involves illegality under some
other statute of the
Commonwealth or a State or Territory or may otherwise be
contrary to public policy evidenced in statute or common law then it may
be held
not to give rise to a ‘benefit’ for that
reason.[22]
- The
other side of the public benefit coin is the risk of ‘detriment to the
public’ under s 90(6) and 90(7). This covers
‘... any impairment to
the community generally, any harm or damage to the aims pursued by the Society,
including as one of
its principal elements the achievement of the goal of
economic efficiency
...’.[23] The
concept of ‘detriment’ is ‘wider than the notion of
anti-competitive effect’, although normally the
most important detriments
will have that character. The relevant detriment flows from the
anti-competitive effect of the conduct
for which authorisation is
sought.[24] Other
detriments which may be intrinsic to and therefore detract from, the claimed
public benefit may also be relevant in the weighing
of that
benefit.[25]
Authorisation – essentially administrative
- Authorisation
does not change the law. It is not a legislative process. The Act provides
that certain of its prohibitions do not
apply to conduct which is authorised.
So it limits its own application. Authorisation is essentially
administrative.
- A
somewhat analogous example of administrative disapplication of a particular
provision of the law existed under provisions of the
Income Tax Assessment
Act 1936 (Cth) governing the rate at which trust income should be taxed.
Sections 99 and 99A of that Act provided for different rates of tax on the same
trust estate. The higher rate applied under s 99A. The section provided,
however, that if the Commissioner thought it unreasonable that the section
should apply, then it would not apply and tax at a different
rate would be
imposed under s 99. The Commissioner was required to have regard to a number of
matters set out in s 99A but also
to ‘such other matters, if any, as he
thinks fit’.
- In
Giris Pty Ltd v Federal Commissioner of Taxation [1969] HCA 5; (1969) 119 CLR 365, the
High Court held s 99A to be valid. Barwick CJ observed that the Commissioner
could choose which section was to apply in the
exercise of what he called
‘a legislative discretion’ (372). He said (at
372):
‘I have been unable to find any content for the word
“unreasonable” in the context of the two sections except
considerations
of a kind upon which a legislature acts in deciding whether an
enactment or its particular terms are or are not unreasonable having
regard to
the interests of the public generally, of the citizen to be affected, of the
revenue and of the requirements of those policies,
political, economic and
fiscal which the Parliament is prepared to
sanction.’
He went further and said, disapprovingly, (at 372):
‘This view of the discretion gives to the Commissioner a wide charter
which it might have been thought he was ill-equipped to
exercise. What he is
required to decide, in my opinion, is in truth a function of the legislature,
rarely delegated to an official.’
The term ‘legislative discretion’ does not seem to have been used
by Barwick CJ in the constitutional sense of legislative
power. It was rather a
way of drawing attention to the width of the Commissioner’s discretion.
He identified, as a vice
of the legislative scheme, that the taxpayer would not
know what impact the law regarding income tax would have upon him. Put another
way, there was no certainty about the rate of income tax that would be levied
upon trust estates where the discretion was invoked.
The question of
predictability and the role of consistency and policy and the use of guidelines
in the exercise of wide discretions
is of significance in this context. It is
also significant for the authorisation process.
- Kitto
J had no difficulty in rejecting the notion that s 99A involved a transfer of
legislative power to the Commissioner. He accepted
the proposition that the
operation of the law with respect to taxation could validly be made to depend
upon the formation of an administrative
opinion or satisfaction upon a question
(at 379). Menzies J described the section as conferring ‘an extraordinary
responsibility
on the Commissioner of Taxation’. He noted the absence of
any ‘common principle’ underlying the factors which
the Commissioner
was required to take into account which would give him a lead to other matters
to which he might have regard. He
said (at 381):
‘The enactment of such a provision can only be regarded as an
acknowledgement by the legislature of its inability to make laws
laying down
prospectively what will give rise to a particular taxation
liability.’
- Windeyer
J saw the Commissioner’s discretion as ‘apparently at large’.
He went on to say (at 384):
‘However I assume that he is to be guided and controlled by the policy
and purpose of the enactment, so far as that is manifest
in it. That would
exclude from his consideration any matter which it would be unlawful for him to
take as a criterion, such as the
State of residence of a trustee or of the
beneficiaries of a trust. It would also, I think, exclude all merely fanciful
and prejudiced
tests which were hypothetically suggested in argument, such as
vocation, religion, colour of skin or
hair.’
The latter observation points to the outer limits of any wide discretion.
Where a term such as ‘public benefit’ is used,
there is necessarily
a link to some criteria which distinguish the good from the bad and the merely
indifferent. This must ultimately
be rooted in a perception of widely shared
community values.
- The
difficulties that the High Court had in discerning the limits of the
Commissioner’s discretion under s 99A which had a relatively
narrow focus
are magnified in the case of the public benefit test in Pt VII which must have a
content sufficiently wide to be capable
of offsetting different kinds of
detriment flowing from the anti-competitive acts of a wide variety of conduct
covered by Pt VII.
- The
nature of authorisation can be examined by asking whether it is a function
exclusively administrative in character or one which
could be undertaken by a
court. Administrative bodies such as the Australian Competition and Consumer
Commission and the Australian
Competition Tribunal do not exercise the judicial
power of the Commonwealth. They cannot do what is reserved to Courts exercising
federal jurisdiction by Chapter III of the Constitution. A judge who sits on
the Australian Competition Tribunal does not act judicially, but in an
administrative capacity. On the other
hand, a court exercising federal
jurisdiction can only act as a court. It cannot engage in administrative
decision making except
such as may be incidental to its judicial role. As Sir
Isaac Isaacs said in 1926:
‘... some matters so clearly and distinctively appertain to one branch
of government as to be incapable of exercise by another.’
[26]
- There
are some classes of decision making however which are administrative when done
by an administrative body and judicial when done
by a court. They are sometimes
called ‘chameleon’ functions. Isaacs J described them thus:
‘Other matters may be subject to no a priori exclusive
delimitation, but may be capable of assignment by Parliament in its discretion
to more than one branch of government.’
[27]
- An
example of a chameleon function is the determination of whether a person is
eligible for extradition. Under the Extradition Act 1988 (Cth) it is
determined at first instance by a magistrate acting, not as a court, but in an
administrative role. The magistrate’s
decision can be reviewed on the
merits by a court exercising federal jurisdiction which is then acting
judicially.[28] The
Registrar of Trade Marks acts administratively when deciding to grant or
withhold registration of a trade mark, but may be reviewed
on the merits (not
merely for error of law) by the court. The function of the court in such a
review is
judicial.[29] For an
administrative function to be capable of changing its character to a judicial
function it should ordinarily involve the application
of legal rules to
ascertained facts, the determination of rights, liabilities or status and the
grant or refusal of relief. This
form of reasoning also applies to the example
given earlier about the enforceability of covenants in restraint of trade. The
legal
rule is that the covenant is unenforceable unless reasonable by reference,
inter alia, to the public interest. The rule is applied
to the particular
covenant involved. It may be that reference is had to factual matters
comprising the context in which the covenant
was created. Although involving a
public interest evaluation, the approach is essentially judicial.
- Authorisation
is administrative in character because it is not concerned with a dispute
between parties or the determination of rights,
liabilities or status. Nor is
it to be compared to a judgment in rem which is good as against the whole
world. An application for authorisation is not a proceeding to resolve a
justiciable controversy.
It may be opposed by particular parties but not
necessarily. The public benefit test invites consideration of the impact of the
proposed conduct on a range of interests and allows for administrative
inquiries. It involves what is sometimes called in public
law discourse
‘polycentric decision making’ which courts are not institutionally
competent, nor constitutionally authorised,
to do. The process of
investigation, receipt of submissions from interested groups and parties, the
consideration of their roles
and interests in the relevant market and the
compromises which may be reflected in conditional authorisations lie beyond the
functions
of courts.
- Courts
have regard to policy considerations in the development of legal standards just
as they may make evaluative and normative judgments.
But these things are done
within the general framework of judicial decision making.
- The
characterisation of authorisation as administrative flows in part from the very
width of the public benefit test and the open-ended
nature of the fact finding
processes associated with it. That in turn raises a question about the extent
to which the Commission
in its authorisation decisions can aspire to
consistency. It raises the related question about the extent to which the
Commission
can establish non-statutory guidelines about its approach to
authorisation in particular classes of case.
The elements of
the authorisation process
- It
has been said by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission that the
authorisation process allows it ‘... to grant
immunity on public benefit
grounds for conduct that might otherwise breach the competition provisions of
the TPA’.[30]
This could be read as suggesting that authorisation is a kind of dispensation
from the rigors of the law. In the Commission’s
paper published in July
2004 it said:
‘The authorisation process is necessarily a thorough and rigorous
process, given that what is being contemplated is immunity
from the
law.’
There can be no complaint about a requirement that the authorisation process
be thorough and rigorous. However the disapplication
of the prohibition under
the Act is contemplated by the Act itself on the application of a public benefit
balancing test. It reflects
a legislative intention that certain types of
anti-competitive conduct should not be subject to the prohibitions if the public
benefit
of their proposed conduct outweighs the anti-competitive detriment or
otherwise satisfies the requirements of authorisation. While
Pt IV of the Act
is directed to the maintenance of workable competition, the authorisation
provisions recognise that legitimate public
benefits can flow from conduct
otherwise prohibited. They recognise that competition is not ‘a theory of
everything’
when it comes to the public interest. Or as a famous American
cosmologist once remarked, ‘There is more to everything than
meets the
eye’. The political pressures to amend the Act in various ways in the
interests of particular groups such as small
business, exemplify that
reality.
- The
proposition that competition, and indeed economic efficiency, is not everything
is reflected in the observations of the Australian
Competition Tribunal in
Qantas. The Tribunal eschewed the notion that the net public benefit
test for authorisation under s 90 has as its sole objective the promotion
of
efficient resource allocation (at [180]):
‘The authorisation provisions of the Act, unlike those of Pt IV, are
not solely concerned with the promotion of competition
or the achievement of a
socially efficient allocation of resources. The test for authorisation does,
after all, provide for a balancing
of public benefit against anti-competitive
detriment, which necessarily calls on us to consider policy imperatives and
broader social
values and balance those against competition
concerns.’
The Tribunal quoted, with approval, the words of the Tribunal in Re
7-Eleven Stores:
‘We cannot rely upon the functioning of competitive markets to deliver
everything ‘of value to the community
generally’.’
- It
is notable in this context that s 90(10) provides for an application for certain
classes of authorisation to be deemed granted
if not determined by the
Commission within a certain timeframe. This arguably evidences a legislative
intention that certain prohibitions
can be disapplied, regardless of the balance
of detriment and benefit, by reason of administrative failure or incapacity.
- A
legal analysis of the decision-making framework within which the Commission
operates under Pt VII reveals a number of elements which
allow for a range of
possible outcomes on any given set of facts. The first is the discretionary
character of the power conferred
upon the Commission by s 88 of the Act to
authorise conduct involves the exercise of a discretion. Section 88(1) begins
with the
words:
“Subject to this Part, the Commission may, upon application by or on
behalf of a corporation, grant an authorisation to the
corporation.’
A similar form of words is used in the other parts of s 88. The discretion
is expressed to be ‘Subject to this Part’.
That requires that the
necessary conditions for its exercise under s 90 must be satisfied. But that
satisfaction does not mandate authorisation. The Commission appears to
have a discretion to refuse authorisation even where the public benefit test has
been satisfied.
For the framing of the test in s 90 is prefaced by the words
‘The Commission shall not make a determination granting an authorisation
... unless it is satisfied ...’.
- What
is the significance of the discretion? Once the Commission is satisfied that
the public benefit of proposed conduct outweighs
its anticompetitive detriment
or is such that the conduct ought to be allowed, there would seem little room
left for any legitimate
basis for refusal of authorisation. The exercise of the
discretion would have to have regard to the stated object of the Act under
s 2,
but that object will already have been taken into account in the public benefit
assessment. A refusal to grant authorisation
despite a positive public benefit
assessment would necessarily have to identify factors extraneous to the public
benefit test, which
warranted refusal of authorisation. It is not easy to
imagine what they would be.
- Where,
as in most cases, neither the apprehended detriment nor the promised benefit is
a certainty, the Commission is required to
have regard to
‘likelihoods’. The Tribunal in QCMA put it thus:
‘We are to be concerned with probable effects rather than with possible
or speculative effects. Yet we accept the view that
the probabilities with
which we are concerned are commercial or economic likelihoods which may not be
susceptible of formal proof.
We are required to look into the future but we can
be concerned only with the foreseeable future as it appears on the basis of
evidence
and argument relating to the particular
application.’
- To
the extent that this assessment of likelihood imported the concept of a balance
of probabilities, it is not reflected in subsequent
judicial construction of
words importing likelihood in the Act. The Tribunal in Qantas applied
what was said about the likelihood of a substantial lessening of competition in
Australian Gaslight Company v Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
(No 3) [2003] FCA 1525 at [348]:
‘The assessment of the risk or real chance of a substantially lessening
of competition cannot rest upon speculation or theory.
To borrow the words of
the Tribunal in the Howard Smith case, the Court is concerned with
‘commercial likelihood relevant to the proposed merger’. The word
‘likely’
has to be applied at a level which is commercially relevant
or meaningful as must be the assessment of the substantial lessening
of
competition under consideration.’
The Tribunal said (at [156]):
‘Thus for a benefit or detriment to be taken into account, we must be
satisfied that there is a real chance, and not a mere
possibility, of the
benefit or detriment eventuating. It is not enough that the benefit or
detriment is speculative or a theoretical
possibility. There must be a
commercial likelihood that the applicants will, following the implementation of
the relevant agreements,
act in a manner that delivers or brings about the
public benefit or the lessening of competition giving rise to the public
detriment.
We must be satisfied that the benefit or detriment is such that it
will, in a tangible and commercially practical way, be a consequence
of the
relevant agreements it carried into effect and must be sufficiently capable of
exposition (but not necessarily quantitatively
so) rather than ephemeral or
illusory, to use the words of the Tribunal in Re Rural Traders Cooperative
(WA) Ltd at 263.’
It can be seen that as in other ‘likelihood’ judgments in the
Act, there is an evaluative and purposive element involved.
- The
level of likelihood of detriment must be relevant to the market with which the
Commission is concerned. Benefit is not a concept
relevant only in a market.
It has a wider application. The assessment of a relevant level of likelihood
where a benefit is concerned
is in that sense more difficult. No doubt, in the
assessment generally a moderate risk of a very significant detriment will weigh
more heavily in the balance than a high risk of a minor detriment.
- The
Tribunal is also required to have regard to ‘all the circumstances’
in each of the authorisation tests prescribed
by the Act. This is hardly a
limiting factor. Of this criterion the Tribunal in Re QIW Ltd (1995) 132
ALR 225 said (at 234):
‘The examination of “all the circumstances” must in our
view involve the tribunal in an examination of matters of
detriment, including
anti-competitive detriment, in order to conclude whether in all the
circumstances there is such a degree of
benefit to the public that the
acquisition should be allowed to proceed
...’
This throws little light upon the range of ‘circumstances’
outside detriment, benefit and likelihood that the Tribunal
is required to
consider.
- Perhaps
one of the most difficult elements of the authorisation process in the
competition test provisions is that which requires
the judgment whether benefit
to the public would ‘outweigh’ anti-competitive detriment. Where
benefit is to be assessed
by reference to criteria of economic efficiency, then
at least benefit and detriment are more or less in the same universe of
discourse.
Where a wider range of benefits is brought into the equation the
concept of ‘weighing’ cannot import a quantitative
basis for
comparison. As the Tribunal said in Qantas (at
[208]):
‘All other things being equal, detailed quantification is the best
option. However, quantification at all costs is not required
by the Act, and
has never been sought by the Tribunal. There are diminishing returns to the
quantification exercise. Benefits should
be quantified only to the extent that
the exercise enlightens the Tribunal more than the alternative of qualitative
explanation.’
And (at [209]):
‘Benefits cannot be quantified in monetary terms, they can still be
claimed in qualitative terms. The authorisation test is,
after all, a balancing
exercise that requires judgment over a wide range of tangible and intangible
factors. The final result will
depend upon the relative weight assigned to each
of these factors.’
- Where
a quantifiable detriment is to be weighed against a quantifiable benefit,
assuming the quantification is real and not just a
cover for qualitative
judgment, then at least there is some conceptual consistency between the
quantities being compared. The exercise
acquires something of an air of
unreality in a quantitative sense when regard is had to possible discounting
based on relative likelihoods
of detrimental and beneficial outcomes. The
assessment of those likelihoods, even if assigned, a number must be qualitative
in the
sense already discussed.
- Where
quantifiable factors are weighed against unquantifiable factors or a mix of
both, the exercise is inescapably one of qualitative
judgment.
- In
relation to the per se prohibitions, the question is whether the public
benefit is such that the conduct ‘should be allowed’. This goes
beyond
the consideration of anti-competitive detriment and requires recognition
of the unqualified nature of the statutory prohibition that
otherwise applies.
The Tribunal observed in Qantas that in a number of previous decisions it
had expressed the view that the test for authorisation is the same whether or
not the provisions
under consideration constitute a contract, arrangement or
understanding governed by s 90(6) or (7), or an exclusionary provision
or
acquisition governed by ss 90(8) or
(9).[31] However in a
later decision in 2004, the Tribunal observed that although weighing of benefit
and detriment was involved in both
tests, it did not follow that they were
precisely the same in all circumstances. While the test under s 90(6) and (7)
is confined
to a consideration of detriment flowing from a lessening of
competition, the test under s 90(8) and (9) may not be so confined and
could
include a broader category of detriment.
[32] The Tribunal in
Qantas did not resolve the question of the correctness of the distinction. That
is because no detriment was put
to it other than detriment arising from a
lessening of competition. As a matter of statutory construction however, there
does seem
to be implicit a distinction reflecting the policies underpinning the
different authorisation tests.
- The
various elements of the authorisation process referred to confer upon the
Commission considerable room to move. The criteria
for decision making that are
set out would all qualify, to a greater or lesser extent, as ‘categories
of meaningless reference’.
That was a term adopted by the late Professor
Julius Stone to describe legal criteria whose application is so vague as not to
be
informed by any meaningful principle. In that sense the authorisation
process involves the application of categories of meaningless
reference. How
then is predictability in its application achieved?
Guidelines,
policies and precedents
- It
is evident that the only way in which predictability can be achieved in this
area of administration of the competition laws is
through the build up of a body
of decisions over many years reflecting generally consistent approaches to like
cases. There is,
however, no doctrine of stare decisis which binds
administrative decision makers. On the other hand, the unequal treatment of
identical cases may give rise to a judicial
review challenge on the basis that
there has been discrimination by reference to some irrelevant consideration.
The regulator may
make lists of things which it has treated in the past, and
generally in the present, treats as benefits and detriments. Given the
scope of
those concepts such a list can never be exhaustive. Nor can it lead to
confident predictions of the relative weightings
accorded to different
combinations of benefit and detriment in particular cases. There is no
principle to be derived from the statute
which confines the inescapably
evaluative and normative and policy judgments which are involved.
- The
publication of policies and guidelines to the way in which the Commission
approaches its task is, of course, perfectly legitimate.
Many administrative
agencies exercising wide statutory discretions publish such guidelines. However
they cannot bind the decision
maker in such a way as effectively to fetter the
narrow the discretion or range of considerations open to its consideration.
- The
build up over time of a body of precedents, the attempt so far as possible to
achieve consistency and the familiarity of the regular
actors with the practices
and approaches of the decision maker will assist in achieving a degree of
predictability.
- The
criteria by which authorisation is given involve categories of meaningless
reference which allow the regulator to make policy-based
choices. But there is
nothing new about that. Judges have been doing it for years.
[1] These words
rephrase the message from Commodore Perry to General Harrison in 1813 after the
Battle of Lake Erie, ‘We have
met the enemy and they are ours.’
[2] R v
Russell [1827] EngR 487; (1827) 6 B & C
566.
[3]
Attorney General v Terry (1874) LR Ch App 423 at 427.
[4] Ibid at
428.
[5] Chitty on
Contracts, Vol 1, General Principles, 29th ed Sweet and
Maxwell 2004 at
16-075.
[6]
Nordenfelt v The Maxim Nordenfelt Guns and Ammunition Co Ltd [1894] UKLawRpAC 52; [1894] AC
535 at 565. See also Esso Petroleum Co Ltd v Harper’s Garage
(Stourport) Ltd [1967] UKHL 1; [1968] AC 269 and the recent discussion of the doctrine in
the High Court in Peters (WA) Ltd v Petersville Ltd [2001] HCA 45; (2001) 205 CLR
126.
[7] Texaco
Ltd v Mulberry Filling Station Ltd [1972] 1 WLR 814 at
827-828.
[8]
Chitty,op cit at 16-094 referring to the Competition Act 1998 (UK) and
Articles 81 and 82 of the Treaty of
Rome.
[9] Halsburys
Laws of England, 4th ed, Vol 47, par
72.
[10]
Halsburys Laws of England, 4th ed, Vol 47, p 408,
Minute Note 5.
[11]
Halsburys Laws of England, 4th ed, Vol 47, par
209.
[12]
Halsburys Laws of England, 4th ed, Vol 47, par
242.
[13]
Trade Practices Act 1965 (Cth) s
50(2).
[14] Trade
Practices Act Review Committee, Report to the Minister of Business and Consumer
Affairs (1976) pars 11.14 and
11.15.
[15] It
has been said that the tests are for all intents and purposes identical –
Re Media Council of Australia (No 2) (1987) ATPR
40-774.
[16]
Re Queensland Co-operative Milling Association Ltd; Re Defiance Holdings Ltd
(1976) 25 FLR
169
[17] Ibid at
182-183.
[18]
Re Howard Smith Industries Pty Ltd (1977) 28 FLR 385; Re Rural Traders
Co-operative (WA) Ltd (1979) 37 FLR 244 and see Qantas Airways Ltd
[2004] A Compt T 9 at [199] excluding certain benefits to foreign
shareholders.
[19]
Breen v Amalgamated Engineering Union [1971] 2 QB 175 at 190 and see
generally Wade and Forsyth, Administrative Law,
(9th Ed, Oxford University Press, 2002) at
356-359.
[20]
Gerlach v Clifton Bricks Pty Ltd (2002) 209 CLR 478 at [69] – [70].
See also Hot Holdings Pty Ltd v Creasy [1996] HCA 44; (1996) 185 CLR 149 at
171.
[21]
Water Conservation and Irrigation Commission (NSW) v Browning (1947) 74
CLR 492 at 505 (Dixon J), 496 (Latham CJ); R v Australian Broadcasting
Tribunal; Ex parte 2HD Pty Ltd [1979] HCA 62; (1979) 144 CLR 45 at 49-50; FAI Insurances
Ltd v Winneke [1982] HCA 26; (1982) 151 CLR 342 at 368 (Mason J); Minister for
Aboriginal Affairs v Peko-Wallsend Ltd (1986) 162 CLR 24 at 40 (Mason J);
O’Sullivan v Farrer [1989] HCA 61; (1989) 168 CLR 210 at 216 and Oshlack v
Richmond River Council [1998] HCA 11; (1980) 193 CLR 72 at
84.
[22]
Hospital Benefit Fund of Western Australia v Australian Competition and
Consumer Commission (1997) 76 FCR
369.
[23] Re
7-Eleven Stores Pty Ltd (1994) ATPR 41-357 at 42,683 and see also Qantas
at [150].
[24]
QCMA at
184.
[25] Re
Southern Cross Beverages Pty Ltd (1981) 50 FLR
176.
[26]
Federal Commissioner of Taxation v Munro [1926] HCA 58; (1926) 38 CLR
153.
[27] Ibid at
178 and see Aston v Irvine [1955] HCA 53; (1955) 92 CLR
353.
[28]
Pasini v United States of Mexico (2002) 209 CLR
246
[29]
Farbenfabriken Bayer Aktiengesellsthaft v Bayer Pharma Pty Ltd (1959) 11
CLR 652; R v Quinn; Ex parte Consolidated Food Corporation [1977] HCA 62; (1977)
138 CLR 1.
[30]
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission – Authorising and Notifying
Collective Bargaining and Collective Boycott Issues
Paper, July 2004 at p
3.
[31] Re
Media Council of Australia (No 2) (1987) 88 FLR 1 at 9; Re 7-Eleven
Stores at
42,654.
[32]
Re Australian Association of Pathology Practices Inc (2004) 206 ALR 71 at
[86] – [93].
AustLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/FedJSchol/2006/24.html